Measuring monetary policy shocks

What are the effects on the economy when the Fed raises interest rates? This is a key question in empirical research, but is notoriously hard to answer. The reason is that when the Fed raises interest rates, it usually does so in anticipation of a stronger economy or rising inflation. If we look at what happens to inflation or output following an interest rate hike, it is impossible to distinguish the effect of the Fed’s actions from the effects of the changing fundamentals that led the Fed to act in the first place. New research by a graduate student at UCSD may have finally solved this problem.

A common approach that recent researchers have taken has been to focus on what happens to interest rates within a narrow window of time, say 30 minutes to one day, around a monetary policy announcement. If the time window is narrow enough, one can make a strong case that the changes in interest rates within that window were caused by the Fed announcement itself and not by some other news hitting the market at the same time. By looking for the effects of those specific, narrow changes in interest rates on the economy, researchers hope to learn about the effects of the Fed’s actions.

However, as noted by Campbell et al. (2012), Nakamura and Steinsson (2018), Cieslak and Schrimpf (2018), and some of my own work as well, this doesn’t really solve the problem if the Fed has some information about economic fundamentals that the market doesn’t. Any news that inflation or output are headed up, whether the news comes from the Fed or any other source, will be a development that raises interest rates. An announcement by the Fed that it is raising interest rates relative to what the market anticipated may cause market participants to conclude that the economy is stronger than they thought, and this could be the primary reason why interest rates respond to the Fed’s announcement.

Campbell et al. (2012) and Nakamura and Steinsson (2018) documented an interesting observation that supports that interpretation. Suppose we take the change in the 3-month-ahead fed funds futures contract on the day of an FOMC announcement, and regress the change in the Blue Chip forecast of inflation that month on that one day’s change in the futures price. The coefficient turns out to be positive– when the Fed surprises the market by raising rates, private analysts revise their forecasts to conclude that inflation is headed higher. That doesn’t mean that when the Fed raises rates, it actually causes inflation to go up (rather than the Fed’s intended effect of bringing inflation down). Instead it suggests that the change in futures prices on that day is mostly reflecting changes in economic fundamentals rather than economic policy. If the Fed signals it is more worried about inflation, private analysts conclude that maybe they should be more worried about inflation as well. Similarly, one finds an unexpected increase in fed funds futures on the day of an FOMC announcement is associated with a decrease in Blue Chip unemployment forecasts. Again, that’s exactly the opposite of the effect expected from a monetary contraction, and is instead exactly the effect predicted if the main thing the Fed is doing is revealing information about economic fundamentals.

Cieslak and Schrimpf (2018) document another interesting fact. A monetary contraction is supposed to raise rates and lower output, both of which should make stock prices lower. But as often as not, one sees stock prices rise on days when the Fed announces higher rates.

A third way to see the issue visually is to look at the cumulative change in fed funds futures over a 12-month period using just the days of FOMC announcements, as shown in the figure below. The Fed was consistently surprising the market with lower interest rates during the recession of 2001. But clearly with hindsight, the Fed was doing this because it saw the economy as weaker than many private analysts recognized at the time. If you look at the correlation between this supposed monetary shock and economic variables of interest over this period, you’re going to find the effect of the recession, not the effect of actions by the Fed.

A number of alternative measures of monetary policy shocks have been proposed by other researchers. One of the more promising ideas was developed by Romer and Romer (2004). They proposed to measure the information about economic fundamentals that the Fed had but the market did not by using the Greenbook forecasts prepared by Fed staff prior to each FOMC meeting. Romer and Romer then used the component of changes in the Fed’s interest rate target that could not be predicted on the basis of Greenbook forecasts. A new paper by UCSD graduate student Xu Zhang looks at this and a number of other proposed measures of monetary shocks. Zhang finds, as other researchers have as well, that while the Romer and Romer measure offers improvements over some of the others, it is still the case that their measure has a positive correlation with revisions in Blue Chip inflation forecasts. And, like the other measures, it still shows a definite trend down during the 2001 recession.

Zhang’s suggested solution begins with the observation by Gurkaynak, Sack and Swanson (2005) that the news revealed by a typical FOMC announcement is multidimensional. The Fed is typically both changing the current interest rate and signaling the changes that are in store for the future. Zhang’s starting point was therefore to look at changes in futures contracts of 5 different maturities– the current and 3-month-ahead fed funds as well as Eurodollars at 2, 3, and 4 quarters ahead– on days of FOMC announcements. For each contract, she regressed that change on the Greenbook forecasts as in Romer and Romer, with the residuals interpreted as the part of that change in rates that could not be attributed to superior Fed information. She then takes the principal component of those 5 residuals as her measure of the shock to monetary policy. The resulting series and twelve-month accumulations are plotted below.


Initial analysis of this measure looks promising. Unlike any other measure that Zhang examined, her measure has a consistently positive correlation with changes in Blue Chip unemployment forecasts at and a negative correlation with changes in Blue Chip inflation forecasts at every horizon. Rate hikes attributed to monetary policy are associated with falling stock prices while rate cuts are associated with rising stock prices more strongly than for any other measure. And unlike all the other measures, her series does not seem to be just another proxy for the state of the business cycle.

I’ll be interested to see what other researchers find with this measure. But my preliminary conclusion is that, if I wanted an empirical measure of true shocks to monetary policy, this is the one I would use.

9 thoughts on “Measuring monetary policy shocks

  1. Moses Herzog

    I’m a slow reader. I’m on page 3 if it gives you any clue. Partly because I was reading the wrong paper while the site was down. But no matter, I’m so slow that probly wouldn’t make a difference anyway. I’m gonna try and get this all read tonight. I’m all out of “bang” drink, and my go to for “bang” is halfway across the metro. I can get it at like $1.48 vs a 1.76 most places. Anyway, hopefully coffee and some kinda sugar crap can get me through this paper and I might have something halfway intelligent to say about it. Miracles can happen to you.

  2. Moses Herzog

    OK, so I read all of this, and I feel I got most of it, although some of the math probably escaped me, but I think I got most of it. I want to “digest” it some more, and give further thoughts beyond this in a later comment, but I have some bi-weekly shopping I need to do, and I want to give my “abbreviated” take on this paper, as I feel the intelligent young lady who did this deserves it.

    My first question is, Why hasn’t Goldman Sachs hired Xu Zhang yet?? Because based on this paper, Goldman Sachs should have offered her a high paying job about 3 years ago. I thought Goldman Sachs was always searching out the very best brains of the world?? Seems Goldman Sachs’ AI recruiting droid missed one:
    https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=zckJVQS6Vo8

    +1 point for young Chinese researchers everywhere, -5 points to Goldman Sachs for not hiring her 3 years ago.

    Oh yeah….. and +0.125 points to crotchety California professor/mentors known for their thoughts on oil prices and “other gunk”. (I say “crotchety” in the most affectionate way possible)

    [edited by JDH]

  3. pgl

    “this doesn’t really solve the problem if the Fed has some information about economic fundamentals that the market doesn’t.”

    Of course suggesting that the FED knows something the market has not realizes is going to drive conservative economists crazy. Of course Wilbur Ross will try to influence the FED to let him trade on inside information!

  4. AS

    Professor Hamilton,
    “She then takes the principal component of those 5 residuals as her measure of the shock to monetary policy. The resulting series and twelve-month accumulations are plotted below.”

    I don’t understand what I am supposed to see from the two charts mentioned above, compared to the other charts.
    Apologies for being slow.

    1. James_Hamilton Post author

      AS: What you’re supposed to see in the first 2 graphs is that the series is declining significantly during the 2001 recession. That’s a problem for the way researchers intend to interpret this series. What you’re supposed to see in the final graph is that the series is much less simply a summary of current business conditions. That’s also confirmed by the various statistical tests that Zhang conducts.

  5. Moses Herzog

    Was trying to find something deep or insightful to say about the paper. Specifically related to the paper, and although I feel I understand it about 85% (the 15% part not understood probably related to regressions and the residuals and stuff like that, that I only semi grasp). Although I suppose you could argue the residuals are pretty damned important if that’s where you draw your measure of monetary “shock” from, but I only “get” this in a vague kind of way. Anyways, I do have something to say related to research choices in a very broad kind of way, not meant as a criticism, but just a kind of “food for thought” or something to ponder.

    There are tons and tons and toms of economic papers rationalizing or trying to improve the process of the Fed’s large scale open market purchases. Now I guess this paper is more related to the federal funds target rate than large scale open market purchases—but they are closely related. And this flood of papers, surplus of papers, or what I might subjectively term superabundance of papers rationalizing the large scale open market purchases often leaves out an important detail that many large TBTF banks and bond “dealers” would rather not discuss. The dangerous credit instruments banks use (many synthetic CDOs and CLOs etc) that banks would rather never ever discuss (or see discussed in research papers). And, usually only during or immediately after the crises, do these things get discussed, when in fact it is these credit instruments and synthetic credit activities that FORCE the usage of emergency large scale open market “asset” purchases to begin with. Or even “emergency” type moves in the discount rate.

    So researchers are discussing how is the best way to apply the Bactine spray and how much Bactine spray to use on a wound but researchers seem to have much less interest in “tough love” research papers to TBTF banks discussing the dangers of the type and amount of credit instruments which created the open ulcer skin wound.

    Now, in this case, it seems like a breakthrough (Xu Zhang’s terrific and impressive paper which she was kind enough to share with us) method of measuring monetary shock has been found, and so in this case the efforts and time were very worthy. And again, I guess Xu Zhang’s paper is dealing more with the federal funds target rate (the more precise scalpel) rather than large scale open market asset purchases (the sledgehammer). But “if I was” a young researcher, I might be more interested in how to stop the crises from happening to begin with than in the proper amount of Bactine for the crises. In which case, as time allowed separate from the focus of my Phd efforts, I might try to sponge up and absorb as much of this gentleman’s writings as possible:
    https://scholar.google.com/citations?user=iZAsYLgAAAAJ&hl=en

    http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/

    Which concludes today’s “mansplaining” lecture from “below average white dude”.

  6. formereconomist

    Doesn’t the problem remain if the FOMC consensus’ forecasts are superior to the Fed Staff’s forecasts? Or if they understand something about financial markets the staff do not? Then the Fed statement does indeed still contain information about the economy. To the extent that we believe in special and talented central bankers who do not mechanistically follow policy rules whose input come from the staff, this may be the case.

  7. anon

    Are the irfs in Figure 11 useful? It looks like they aren’t as bad as Figure 10, but it’s not like they are what we would expect either.

  8. Luca Palasti

    The general idea of the article seemed interesting, however I am quite uncertain about the real power of Fed’s announcements on interest rates. I believe that the changes can be highly predicted, so their effects already start to unfold before any news appear from the Fed.

Comments are closed.