Exchange Rate Regimes and the Global Financial Cycle

Relevant or Irrelevant?

The highly integrated nature of the global financial system was amply demonstrated, if we needed any reminder, by the turmoil in emerging market currency and bond markets in the wake of Fed Chairman Bernanke’s statements regarding the normalization of U.S. monetary policy, i.e., the “taper tantrum”. Following close on the heels of complaints about unconventional monetary policy implementation in the preceding years, it is clear that – at a minimum – policymakers in emerging market economies perceive a high and increasing vulnerability to the whims of the global financial system.

The idea that the monetary policies of financial center countries have large spillover effects on the smaller economies is not new. During the mid-1990’s, when advanced economy central bankers raised policy rates, after several years of negative real interest rates, similar complaints were lodged, and some may partly trace the financial crises in Latin America and subsequently in East Asia to the cycle in core country policy interest rates. One key difference is that in the earlier episode’s aftermath, the semi-fixed exchange rate regimes were tagged as a contributing factor. In contrast, countries adhering to a variety of exchange rate regimes all experienced challenges in insulating their economies in the most recent episode. This has led to a grand debate about the continued relevance of the “impossible trinity” or “monetary trilemma”.

Since Mundell (1963) outlined the hypothesis of the monetary trilemma, fundamental policy management in the open economy has been viewed as policy trade-offs among the choices of monetary autonomy, exchange rate stability, and financial openness (e.g., Aizenman, et al. (2010, 2011, 2013), Obstfeld (2014), Obstfeld, et al. (2005), and Shambaugh (2004)). The hypothesis and its extensions suggest a continuous trade off between the three trilemma dimensions, with the possibility that a fourth policy goal, financial stability, may augment it and turn it into a quadrilemma, where international reserves may play a role as buffers.

In contrast, in the aftermath of the global financial crisis (GFC), Rey (2013) concluded that the economic center’s (CE) monetary policy influences other countries’ national monetary policy mostly through capital-flows, credit growth, and bank leverages, making the types of exchange rate regime of the non-CEs irrelevant. In other words, the countries in the periphery (PH) are all sensitive to a “global financial cycle” irrespective of exchange rate regimes. In this view, the “trilemma” reduces to an “irreconcilable duo” of monetary independence and capital mobility. Consequently, restricting capital-mobility maybe the only way for non-CE countries to retain monetary autonomy. The recent experience of Brazil, India, Indonesia, South Africa, and Turkey – the “Fragile Five” – during the so called taper tantrum may make for many observers the “irreconcilable duo” view convincing.

In Aizenman, Chinn and Ito (2015) we investigate whether Rey’s prematurely predicted the end of the trilemma. Inferences based data drawn from times of heightened volatility emanating from the center might be modified once we examine how the propagation of large shocks from the CE can be affected by economic structures and measures of the trilemma variables. In a world of more than hundred countries, one ignores heterogeneity at one’s own risk. For instance, the trade-offs facing the OECD countries may differ from those facing manufacturing based or commodity based emerging markets economies and developing countries. Furthermore, large shocks arising from the EC during the global financial crisis and the Euro debt crisis may have altered the transmission dynamics, especially in comparison to the preceding decade of illusory tranquility.

Figure 1 illustrates the 36- month rolling correlations of domestic money market rates with the U.S. money market rate for developed countries (IDC), developing countries (LDC), and emerging market economies (EMG), and China, from 1990 to 2013. For developed economies, the correlation between domestic and the U.S. policy interest rates is high and hovers at relatively high levels in the last decade. In contrast, developing countries tend to retain high monetary independence from the U.S., while emerging market monetary policy independence occupies a middle ground. All the correlations fluctuate, but experience two pronounced dips in recent years, one in 2005 and the other at the time of the global financial crisis. These two dips correspond to rapid changes in the U.S. Federal funds rate.

ACI15_1

Figure 2 depicts correlations of long-term interest rates. Again, the long-term interest rates of industrialized countries register high correlations with that of the U.S., particularly in the first half of the sample period, though the correlation has been on a rising trend again in recent years. Developing countries experience relatively high correlations in the early 2000s but since the late 2000s, the correlations appear to be trendless for these countries. Long-term interest rates across countries, including both developed and developing countries, were highly correlated during the Great Moderation period.

ACI15_2

Figure 3 is an interesting picture. It illustrates the comparable correlations of stock market price indexes (expressed in local currency) with the U.S. index. Since the mid-2000s, all the country groups have maintained high levels of correlations of stock market price indexes with the U.S. stock market, with some tail-off since the global financial crisis.

ACI15_3

What do these figures tell us? Broadly speaking, the extent of correlations is the highest for stock market price movements, followed by the long-term and short-term interest rates. Given short-term interest rates bear lowest levels of risks, we may conjecture that the prices of assets with higher risk tend to be more highly correlated with that of the United States. Of course, these graphical depictions do not provide conclusive evidence, particularly since we have not controlled for any number of important factors, e.g., the policy regimes, macroeconomic conditions, the extent of trade linkage, the level of institutional development and size of financial markets, and global market conditions. Many studies such as Ahmed and Zlate (2013), Forbes and Warnock (2010), Fratzscher (2011), and Ghosh, et al. (2012) have documented the importance of global factors such as advanced economy interest rates and global risk appetite in affecting capital flows to small open economies. Nonetheless, these studies have also highlighted that domestic, country-specific factors also retain importance. In particular, the institutional and macroeconomic policy frameworks of the emerging market economies also determine the variations in flows.

Methodology

Given this context, we focus on the questions of why movements in the major advanced economies often have large effects on other financial markets, how these cross-market linkages have changed over time, and what kind of factors contribute to explaining the sensitivity to the movements in the major economies. More specifically, we will conduct an empirical analysis on what determines the sensitivity of economies to factors pertaining to the core economies in the world, namely, the U.S., the Euro area, Japan, and China. For the last two decades, the Chinese economy has been growing at impressive rates and quickly moving upward on the development ladder. However, its financial markets may not be developed or sophisticated to the extent of becoming the center of global financial cycles. Despite data limitations as well as China’s relatively short tenure as one of the G3 countries, we will also examine whether our results are sensitive to the inclusion of China as one of the center economies.

For our empirical exploration, we employ an estimation process similar to that employed by Forbes and Chinn (2004), which is composed of two steps of estimations. First, we investigate the degree to which the sensitivity of several important financial variables to global, cross country, and domestic factors. Second, treating the estimated sensitivity as a dependent variable, we examine their determinants among a number of country-specific variables. In so doing, we disentangle roles of countries’ macroeconomic conditions or policies, real or financial linkage with the center economy, or the level of institutional development of the countries.

Results

We find that for most of the financial variables we examine, the strength of the links with the center economies have been the dominant factor over the last two decades. The influence of global financial factors, for which we use VIX and Ted spread, has been increasing since around the time of the global financial crisis. The results we obtain suggest that, across different financial linkages, higher levels of direct trade linkage, financial development, and gross national debt all tend to lead to stronger financial linkages between the sample countries and the three center economies. Open macro policy arrangements such as the exchange rate regime and financial openness also affect the extent of financial linkage both directly and indirectly, i.e., interactively with other macroeconomic or institutional variables. Specifically, we do find that the types of exchange rate regimes do affect the extent of sensitivity to changes in financial conditions or policies in the center economies.

Rey’s (2013) result may reflect the dominance of the US leverage and deregulation policies that contributed to the GFC, as well as the dominance of the Fed’s policies in charting the onset of the tenuous recovery from the GFC. While there is no way for emerging markets to hide from the policies and challenges of the core, the details of the transmission of shocks and the resultant volatility are determined by the trilemma logic. Hence, the open macro policy choice is “still” dictated by the hypothesis of the trilemma. Therefore, the news about the irrelevance of exchange rate changes may have been exaggerated.

Reference

Ahmed, S. and A. Zlate. 2013. “Capital Flows to Emerging Market Economies: A Brave New World?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System International Finance Discussion Papers, #1081. Washington, D.C.: Federal Reserve Board (June).
Aizenman, J., M. D. Chinn, and H. Ito, 2015. “Monetary Policy Spillovers and the Trilemma in the New Normal: Periphery Country Sensitivity to Core Country Conditions,” NBER Working Paper No. 21128.
Aizenman, J. and H. Ito. 2013. Forthcoming in the Journal of International Money and Finance. Also available as NBER Working Paper #19448 (September 2013).
Aizenman, J., M. D. Chinn, and H. Ito. 2011. “Surfing the Waves of Globalization: Asia and Financial Globalization in the Context of the Trilemma,” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, vol. 25(3), p. 290 – 320 (September).
Aizenman, J., Menzie D. Chinn, and H. Ito. 2010. “The Emerging Global Financial Architecture: Tracing and Evaluating New Patterns of the Trilemma Configuration,” Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 615–641.
Forbes, K. J. and M. D. Chinn. 2004. “A Decomposition of Global Linkages in Financial Markets over Time,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, August, 86(3): 705–722.
Forbes, K. J. and F. E. Warnock, 2012. Capital Flow Waves: Surges, Stops, Flight, and Retrenchment. Journal of International Economics, 88(2), 235-251.
Fratzscher, M. 2011. “Capital Flows, Push Versus Pull Factors and the Global Financial Crisis,” NBER Working Paper 17357 (Cambridge: NBER).
Ghosh, A. R., J. Kim, M. Qureshi, and J. Zalduendo, 2012. Surges. IMF Working Paper WP/12/22.
Gourinchas PO and H Rey, 2014, “External Adjustment, Global Imbalances, Valuation Effects,” in Handbook of International Economics, Gopinath, Helpman and Rogoff eds.
Mundell, R.A. 1963. Capital Mobility and Stabilization Policy under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates. Canadian Journal of Economic and Political Science. 29(4): 475–85.
Obstfeld, M. 2014. “Trilemmas and Tradeoffs: Living with Financial Globalization”, mimeo, University of California, Berkeley.
Obstfeld, M., J. C. Shambaugh, and A. M. Taylor. 2005. “The Trilemma in History: Tradeoffs among Exchange Rates, Monetary Policies, and Capital Mobility.” Review of Economics and Statistics 87 (August): 423–438.
Rey, H. 2013. “Dilemma not Trilemma: The Global Financial Cycle and Monetary Policy Independence,” prepared for the 2013 Jackson Hole Meeting.
Shambaugh, J. C., 2004. The Effects of Fixed Exchange Rates on Monetary Policy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (1), 301-52.

3 thoughts on “Exchange Rate Regimes and the Global Financial Cycle

  1. Ricardo

    Menzie,

    Good post.

    Reading James Grant’s MONEY OF THE MIND it came home to me in a stronger way how significantly economics analysis, Whether demand based (Keynesian, monetarist) or supply based (Austrian, classical) a focus on money has pushed out most analysis of fiscal policy forced on economies by world governments. This really came home to me when discussing with advocates of the Federal Reserve about economic recessions pre-FED (earlier than 1914) versus post-FED (after 1914). As Grant’s book reveals there is actually not much difference between pre- and post-FED recessions and it also reveals that almost all economic declines came not from monetary changes but from fiscal changes: government interventions, fraud, bad business management, credit manipulation and over-extension.

    If one understands that money is only a medium of exchange this becomes easier to understand. Because the heart of economic activity is the exchange of real goods and money is only a tool to facilitate trade more efficiently, traders very quickly adapt to monetary changes. Yes, monetary changes can inject distortions into the economic system but they are usually short-lived. On the other hand fiscal changes often have very long ranging impacts on economies.

    A great modern example of this is Obamacare. Was signed by President Obama in March of 2010. It is now more than 5 years later and the most far-reaching aspects of the law have still not been defined or implemented. For 5 years businesses have been unsure of the most common and often most significant cost to doing business, their labor costs. Obamacare has a strangle-hold on the economy not because of its provisions as much as because of its unknowns.

    Government interventions and changes have been the greatest cause of economic declines over the whole world. Monetary changes pale in comparison.

  2. Ricardo

    Here is what happens when real world economics clashes with Ivory Tower economics. Remember, austerity is not an economic system but a consequence of failed economic policy. Next month Greece should be officially bankrupt.

    With Money Drying Up, Greece Is All but Bankrupt

    “These projects are our lifeline,” said Mr. Bakoyannis, who has seen his infrastructure budget cut to €12 million from €65 million in the past four years. “It’s not about Keynesian politics anymore — it’s about finding enough money to repair a simple road.”

Comments are closed.