Guest Contribution: “Terms of Trade Shocks, Competitiveness and Stability: The Role of Foreign Asset Management”

Today we are fortunate to have a guest contribution written by Joshua Aizenman, Dockson Chair in Economics and International Relations. This post is based on a presentation at the Society for the Study of Emerging Markets Panel session, AEA meetings, Boston, January 3, 2015.


The global proliferation of Sovereign Wealth Funds continues [see Figure 1], and includes by now growing number of manufacturing and non-commodity countries [China, Hong Kong, Korea, Singapore, France, Ireland, and others]. Recent research reviewed at the AEA 2015 Boston Meeting suggests that Sovereign Wealth Funds [SWFs] may provide a new margin of stabilization [see the enclosed PP file]. This role is of greater relevance for Inflation Targeting [IT] countries and in periods of heightened volatility. IT regimes may relegate the goal of real exchange rate stabilization and counter-cyclical fiscal policy to its SWF, via a fiscal rule. While international reserves managed by the central bank have comparative advantage in dealing with balance sheet exposure, the SWF deals with longer term saving, and fiscal stabilization. The possible gains of greater division of effort towards stabilization between the central bank and the fiscal authorities apply to all countries with functioning institutions. We validate the growing importance of liquidity management via SWFs for Emerging Markets. These policies mitigate the transmission from terms of trade shocks to the real exchange rate and, thereby, stabilize the domestic economy.

aizenman_map

Figure 1: Sovereign Wealth Fund Assets Map Red = Oil & Gas Blue = NonOil & Gas. Source: Sovereign Wealth Fund Institute / Data from October 2014

This division of labor is consistent with Tinbergen rule in policy design: to reach n targets, one may use n independent instruments. International reserves are useful in dealing with balance sheet exposure, aiming at short and intermediate run stabilization objectives. Yet, hoarding international reserves is not a panacea, as the opportunity cost of reserves imposes a fiscal cost, and hoarding reserves may require sterilization to mitigate their inflationary consequence. Thereby, an inflation targeting regime may relegate the goal of real exchange rate stabilization to its sovereign wealth fund, as part of a fiscal rule aiming at achieving counter-cyclical policy stance. Such a fund may have greater risk tolerance, and its accumulation or decumulation impacts directly the fiscal stance and the real exchange rate.
The gains of combining IT with a fiscal counter-cyclical rule may apply to most countries with functioning institutions, beyond commodity countries managing SWF. The logic of linking country’s buffer funds [international reserves, SWF, public debt] with the fiscal budget can be applied to any country, once we recognize that the market value of sovereign debt is akin to Sovereign Liability Fund – a negative SWF. Similarly, stabilizing the economy in the presence of volatile CTOT and other shocks, aiming at country-cyclical policy is a worthy goal for all countries. While properly managed IT deals with inflation and price stability, generically IT and Taylor rules do not suffice to stabilize both output and inflation. The logic of Tinbergen’s rules of policy design imply that at times of large and persistent shocks, IT rules should be complemented with fiscal rules, as has been clearly illustrated by Chile and several other countries.

The presentation is here.


This post written by Joshua Aizenman.

3 thoughts on “Guest Contribution: “Terms of Trade Shocks, Competitiveness and Stability: The Role of Foreign Asset Management”

  1. Thorstein Veblen

    I think I missed what the interesting point of this article is supposed to be. Of course Sovereign Wealth Funds are used as a tool of monetary policy, but the logic is beyond the pale of what Aizenman guesses at. Oil rich countries like Norway and oil-poor countries like China are accumulating SWT/FR for essentially the same reason — Norway fears Dutch disease and realizes oil won’t last forever, and China wants to undervalue its currency to subsidize manufacturing and bring peasants out of the forest.

    Other issue is that even many countries which say they have an IT regime in practice target the exchange rate as a primary tool to control inflation/output. Also not sure I see the value of thinking about fiscal deficits as “negative Sovereign Wealth Funds”, but thanks for the idea.

  2. Tom

    So if I understand right the author is suggesting keeping SWFs liquid and using them as a fiscal countercyclical. EG Russia which at least purports that its SWFs are liquid should be spending them heavily on public budgets, not using them to bail out banks or state companies. And countries like Malaysia or Singapore that use their SWFs as strategic investment vehicles largely in the domestic economy should stop doing that and switch into liquid assets.

    I guess I don’t see much difference between that and hoarding CB reserves. Either way, in crisis somebody’s selling the FX assets and shlepping domestic currency to the state budget. Moving that function from the CB to the SWF doesn’t really change anything in practice.

    Re: “Indeed, it’s far from obvious why both in the US and the Eurozone, the burden of stabilization during the past five years has have been allocated mostly to the central bank” – I though it was obvious: the US and EA CBs both happened to be excepted from political gridlock.

  3. Johnny

    If Josh believes in the Tinbergen rule, then everything is lost. It cannot make sense to have more than one instrument address a particular objective because one of the instruments has to be better than the other. But anyway, his post is so overly “posh” formulated, the average Joe and Menzie will think Josh is very clever, and that’s what’s all about, isn’t it ?

Comments are closed.